The Application of Public Choice Theory
to Science and Engineering Policy
Barry S. Fagin
Thayer School of Engineering, Dartmouth College
Hanover, NH 03755
barry.fagin@dartmouth.edu
603-646-3060
ABSTRACT
Public choice theory has made a valuable contribution
to our understanding of public policy.
In our judgment, this contribution has been underappreciated by the
science and engineering policy community.
We give a brief overview of the key elements of public choice theory and
discuss its application to science policy.
Based on its predictive power and relevance to contemporary politics, we
recommend that it be taught to engineering students, particularly those
interested in policy issues.
1.0 Introduction
Through
the early 1970's, public policy models were formed around the notion of
government as a "superindividual", one embodying the interests of
society as a whole and capable of correcting the effects of market failure
(Gwartney and Wagner 1988). Accordingly,
the attention of most researchers was focused on the identification of market
imperfections, which were then used to identify corrective policy directives
for government action.
This
view was challenged in the late 70's and early 80's with the development of
public choice theory by James Buchanan, (Buchanan and Tollison 1984), for which
he received the 1986 Nobel Prize in Economics.
Public choice theory applies the tools of economic analysis to political
behavior, in an attempt to explain the functioning of political
institutions. This model permits the
understanding of "political failure", in a similar fashion to the
concept of market failure developed by classical economics.
The
challenge of public choice theory to conventional policy making has, we will
suggest, important implications for science and engineering policy, and in
particular for engineering educators who teach public policy. In this paper, we will discuss these
implications by showing some examples of the predictive value of public choice
theory in science and engineering policy.
We will offer our suggestions for new material for students, and
conclude with directions for future work.
2.0 Essential Features of Public Choice
Theory
Public choice theory attempts to analyze public
behavior in the same manner that economics analyzes private behavior. Accordingly, many of its key features are
similar:
1) People act to
maximize utility in their public capacities as well as their private ones. This means that voters are assumed to
make choices that are expected to maximize benefits to them or minimize
costs. Equally importantly, agents of
government are expected to behave similarly.
We
note that it is a gross misinterpretation of these assumptions to say that they
preclude altruistic and compassionate behavior in the public sector, any more
than they preclude altruistic and compassionate behavior in the private sector. These assumptions do imply, however, that
people's willingness to engage in both
egocentric and altruistic political behavior changes in a predictable way in
response to incentives, in a way similar to their private behavior.
This
assumption, in turn, has important consequences:
2) In
response to incentives, people may engage in rent-seeking behavior. Rent-seeking
is the economic term used to describe attempts by individuals to use the
political process to obtain gains for themselves at the expense of others. Individuals may or may not find rent-seeking
profitable, depending on the political incentive structures they face. Examples of rent-seeking include lobbying for
preferential tax treatment, protection from competition, subsidies,
industry-specific tariffs, and so forth.
Rent-seeking
is economically inefficient, but according to public choice theory it is an
inevitable by-product of human organization if constitutional and governmental
arrangements permit the power of the state to be used to harm some and benefit
others. In our modern democracy,
rent-seeking behavior generally manifests itself in the form of special
interest groups seeking legislative privilege, either by lobbying for special
legislation or by seeking increased allocations of public resources. In both cases, the benefits to the recipients
are concentrated, while the costs to the taxpayer or consumer are diffuse. This, according to public choice theory, is
due to the incentive structure under which American government currently
operates.
3) To the
extent that public policy recommendations ignore human self-interest and the
incentive structure under which they operate, they will fail to have the
intended normative consequences. Since in the vast majority of cases public policy is
carried out by agents of government, it is likely to fail if it assumes
well-informed and altruistic behavior on their part and on the part of those
who would be affected by the policy. In
fact, many public choice economists have argued that the unintended
consequences of legislation, taxation, or other governmental activity can
decrease social utility to below the point when the activity was first
initiated.
3.0 The Predictive Value of Public Choice
Theory and Implications for Science Policy
The
assumptions of public choice theory are not axioms that must be accepted as
self-evident. They are empirically
testable, and considerable research effort has been expended in determining
their validity in the "real world".
For a survey of the literature,
the reader is referred to (Mitchell 1983). Our concern, however, is with the application
of public choice theory to science and engineering policy, an area we believe
has received insufficient attention from public choice theorists. In our judgment, the best work in this regard
is (Martino 1992), written by a physical scientist.
We
believe the predictions made by public choice theory are borne out by an
examination of science policy decisions over the past few decades, particularly
where the federal funding of scientific activity is concerned. We present a few examples here.
3.1 The Political Funding of Science
The
basic argument for federal funding of science concerns the inability of
individual firms to appropriate the results of their research, and was first
proposed by Kenneth Arrow in (Arrow 1962). Under certain conditions, firms may
not be able to recover the potential benefits from research due to difficulties
associated with keeping the research secret from competitors and other external
factors. These firms may then
underinvest in research, requiring government funding to make up for the lost
social benefits.
Public
choice theory, however, would suggest that since government funds would be
collected and distributed through the political process, it is important to
consider the incentives of the agents involved in the process when examining
the consequences of federal funding of science.
The self interest postulate, for example, suggests that politicians
would face strong incentives to use federal funds earmarked for science to
support reelection efforts. By
concentrating the benefits on desired recipients, typically in their home
state, and by diffusing the costs over a large taxpayer base, legislators
pursue their own self interest (and, in all fairness, those of at least some
voters), at the expense of overall social welfare. This process has become known as
"porkbarrel science" (Martino 1992).
In
fact, this behavior is markedly visible today.
The 1991 budgets for the Departments of Energy, Defense, and
Agriculture, for example, contained over
a quarter of a billion dollars for non-peer reviewed earmarked
appropriations for scientific projects (Marshall and Hamilton 1990). This "academic pork" flowing
directly to universities creates tremendous incentives to rent-seek. This is discussed in the next section.
3.2 Incentives
to Rent-Seek Among Researchers and Institutions
The
federal government provides approximately 50% of the funds for research and
development in the United States (Martino 1992), and a much higher percentage
of all research funds at American universities.
Whether these funds are appropriated directly or peer reviewed, the
existence of a large federal presence in science funding creates tremendous
incentives for both individuals and institutions to rent-seek. The pressures on faculty at all ranks to
submit grants to federal agencies, for example, are well known to any
professor.
Most
of us too, I suspect, have been asked at one time or another to show support
for increased appropriations for agencies that fund our work. The American Physical Society, for example,
recently distributed an electronic communiqué informing researchers that the
Administration's requested increase in the Research and Related Activities for
NSF had been reduced from 18% to 10%, and urged recipients to "alert
Senate Appropriators to [their]
concerns" (American Physical Society 1993). While anecdotal, I
suspect this evidence is typical of that encountered by most researchers at one
time or another who have been asked to support increased federal funding of
science.
A
much stronger incentive to rent-seek, however, exists at the institutional
level, provided by existing arrangements to support "indirect cost"
recovery. Indirect costs, because they
are borne by the federal government, create a different set of incentives than
funds provided to universities by private industry. This latter group is not concerned with
indirect or direct costs, but only with the research being purchased. If a private company or foundation does not
believe it is supporting research in a cost effective manner, it will use its
resources elsewhere.
By
contrast, federal funds award a blanket percentage of direct research costs to
universities, at a rate negotiated with one of a few federal agencies. This functions as a subsidy for the modern
research university, and creates strong incentives to rent seek by increasing
the recovery rate. In fact, indirect
cost rates have increased dramatically since the federal government assumed a
major role in supporting research. The
percentage of NIH funds going to indirect costs, for example, has doubled in
the two decades since 1966 (National Science Board 1987). Other studies show similar increases,
increases greater than both the inflation-indexed GNP and federal expenditures
(Chubin and Robinson 1992).
Attempts
to slow the growth of indirect costs meet, as predicted by public choice
theory, with vocal protests from the affected groups (Norman 1986). As a public choice economist and former NSF
official jointly observed:
"The university-based scientific-research cadre
is increasingly linked to federal monies, to the point that some regard their
support as an entitlement, and others, whose positions rely on federal 'soft
money', have grown ever more responsive to the "needs" of the funding
bureaucracy. This dependency promotes
extreme fear of loss of funding ..."
(Aronson and Sommer 1987)
This
phenomenon is particularly pronounced at the top fifty research universities,
which have received more than 2/3 of all federal monies allocated to academic
science. Aronson and Sommer also note
that the list of the top 100 universities for receipt of federal funds has
averaged one replacement per year over the past twenty years. This is a rate
considerably lower than, for example, the top 100 entries on the Fortune 500
list of America's largest companies.
Finally,
with regard to indirect costs, it has been our experience that researchers tend
to support lower indirect costs, whereas administrators do not. This dichotomy has been reported elsewhere
(Martino 1992). In our judgment, the continuing presence of a source of tension
between researchers and administrators at universities is not, we believe,
symptomatic of good science policy, and is an example of an unintended policy
consequence predicted by public choice theory.
3.3 Other Aspects
Public
choice theory predicts many other aspects of the government funding of science,
including
1) Increased red tape and reporting requirements
2) Increased pressure to allocate research funds
geographically
to achieve "fairness"
3) Strong incentives favoring applied research over
basic research
4) Strong incentives favoring low risk research to
high risk research.
Briefly,
these issues arise from the incentive structures faced by members of the
bureaucracy, elected officials, and voters as they interact through the
political process. Increased red tape
and reporting requirements evolve through the desire of both bureaucratic
officials to expand their influence and of elected officials attempting to
respond to taxpayers to ensure their funds are used wisely. "Fairness" questions arise whenever
federal funds are at issue, since there is no reason to expect meritorious
research sites to be distributed on a geographically even basis. Applied research is seen by legislators as
giving increased likelihood of results that are visible to constituents and can
increase the chances of reelection, while risk aversion can be seen as the
approach most likely to maximize the utility of agency managers and
politicians, neither of whom wish to be seen as managing the taxpayers money
unwisely (Cohen and Noll 1991).
3.4 A Counterexample: The Congressional Testimony of
T.J. Rogers
Public
choice theory, like any other social science, does not posit universally
applicable rules for human behavior.
Counterexamples to the predictions made by the naive application of
public choice theory can indeed be found.
One recent example concerns the testimony of T.J. Rogers before the U.S.
House Committee on Science, Space, and Technology. Rogers is president and CEO of Cypress Semiconductor
Inc. and was asked by the House to share his perspectives on the
Administration's proposed "information superhighway".
Surprisingly,
Rogers' testimony explicitly denounces rent-seeking. He stresses repeatedly that neither he nor
his company are interested in special benefits, but are instead more concerned
with the reduction of generally harmful governmental activity. Nor is he alone in this regard. Other CEO's and entrepreneurs in Silicon
Valley have voiced similar sentiments. A
complete copy of Rogers' testimony and the views of similar entrepreneurs is
available in (Rogers 1993). We mention
it here to caution against the naive application of public choice principles,
and to encourage speculation as to whether the political and social culture of
entrepreneurs and/or silicon valley may provide different influences than those
predicted by public choice theory.
4.0 Implications for Engineering Education
and Public Policy
It is our judgment that the predictive value of public
choice theory is sufficiently high that it should be incorporated into public
policy curricula at engineering schools.
It suggests, among other things, a healthy skepticism towards the
efficacy of government activity in science and engineering and an increased
awareness of the shortcomings of the political processes inherent in solving
technical problems.
We
cannot as yet present a detailed list of curricular recommendations. However, should students in an engineering
class be debating a solution to a public policy problem, we believe that the
key elements of public choice theory could be brought to bear by suggesting the
following topics for discussion:
1) Will the proposed solution require the collection
and/or disbursement of resources?
2) If so, will the resources be collected and
disbursed through government agencies?
3) If so, what kind of incentives will the individuals
charged with implementing this solution face?
4) Will the resulting solution encourage rent-seeking
behavior?
5) What will happen to any proposed institutional and
regulatory structures once the problem is solved?
6) In light of the incentive structures created, what
is the likelihood that negative externalities of the proposed solution will
exceed the negative externalities of the problem it was intended to solve?
7) Is there a way to alter the incentive structure
faced by the participants to permit an alternative solution?
We
believe these and similar questions could be profitably discussed in many
engineering and science policy case studies, with fruitful and surprising
results.
5.0 Conclusions
Until
approximately 20 years ago, public policy models viewed government as
essentially a neutral actor, capable of assessing social costs and benefits and
intervening in cases of market failure.
The deficiencies of this model were indicated by proponents of public
choice theory, who applied the tools of economic analysis to individuals acting
in their public capacities. The
resulting model has, we believe, strong predictive power, particularly when
applied to the federal government in the 1990's.
In
our judgment, public choice theory has received insufficient attention from
engineering educators and researchers interested in public policy. The reasons for this are difficult to
ascertain, although we speculate that they are due at least in part to
difficulty in bridging the cognitive gap between the social and physical
sciences. But whatever the cause, we
believe public choice theory has a useful contribution to make to the teaching
of public policy.
Accordingly,
we believe that science and engineering schools should begin the incorporation
of public choice theory into their curriculum, and have presented some sample
discussion questions to motivate basic issues. Engineers interested in public
policy will, we believe, propose better technological solutions to social
problems if equipped with the tools of public choice theory.
6.0 References
Aronson, Peter and Sommer, John, "Science and
Technology Policy: Public Choice and Private Response", Liberty Fund Symposium
on The Academy, Liberty, and the State, Oakland CA, 1987.
Arrow, Kenneth, "Economic Welfare and the
Allocation of Resources for Invention", in National Bureau of Economic
Research, The Rate and Direction of
Inventive Activity, Princeton
University Press, Princeton NJ, 1962.
American Physical Society ALERT, Electronic
Communication to American Physical Society Congressional Volunteers from
opa@aps.org, June 8 1993.
Buchanan, James and Tollison, Robert, "Theory of
Public Choice II", University of Michigan Press, © 1984, ISBN 0472100408.
Chubin, Daryl and Robinson, Elizabeth,
"Accounting for the Costs of Research: Some Policy Rethinking", Science and Public Policy, 3 June 1992, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp 181-185.
Cohen, Linda and Noll, Roger, "The Technology
Pork Barrel", The Brookings Institution, © 1991, ISBN 0815715080.
Gwartney, James and Wagner, Richard, "Public
Choice and Constitutional Economics",
JAI Press Inc., © 1988, ISBN 0892329351
Marshall, Eliot and Hamilton, David, "A Glut of
Academic Pork", Science, 23 November 1990, Vol. 250, pp 1072-1073.
Martino, Joseph, "Science Funding",
Transaction Publishers, ©1992, ISBN 1560000333.
Mitchell, William, "Fiscal Behavior of the Modern
Democratic State: Public Choice Perspectives and Contributions", in Political Economy: Recent Views, pp 69-114. Edited by L. Wade, Sage Publishing Co., Los
Angeles CA, 1983.
National Science Board, "Science and Engineering
Indicators -- 1987", Washington DC, US Government Printing Office.
Norman, Colin "University Groups Protest Cost
Cuts", Science, 7 March 1986, Vol. 231, pp 1059-1060.
Rogers, T.J., "High Tech Hoax", Reason,
July 1993, Vol. 25 No. 3, pp 24-33.
Sommer, Jack, "Distributional Character and
Consequences of the Public Funding of Research", Conference on
Intellectual Freedom and Government Sponsorship of Higher Education, 1987.